Corporate Tax Integration: In Brief (CRS Report for Congress)
Premium Purchase PDF for $24.95 (10 pages)
add to cart or
subscribe for unlimited access
Pro Premium subscribers have free access to our full library of CRS reports.
Subscribe today, or
request a demo to learn more.
Release Date |
Oct. 31, 2016 |
Report Number |
R44671 |
Report Type |
Report |
Authors |
Jane G. Gravelle, Senior Specialist in Economic Policy |
Source Agency |
Congressional Research Service |
Summary:
In January 2016, Senator Orrin Hatch, chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, announced
plans for a tax reform that would explore corporate integration. Corporate integration involves the
elimination or reduction of additional taxes on corporate equity investment that arise because
corporate income is taxed twice, once at the corporate level and once at the individual level.
Traditional concerns are that this system of taxation is inefficient because it (1) favors
noncorporate equity investment over corporate investment, (2) favors debt finance over equity
finance, (3) favors retained earnings over dividends, and (4) discourages the realization of gains
on the sale of corporate stock. Increasingly, international concerns such as allocation of
investment across countries, repatriation of profits earned abroad, shifting profits out of the
United States and into tax havens, and inversions (U.S. firms using mergers to shift headquarters
to a foreign country) have become issues in any tax reform, corporate integration included.
This report summarizes findings in CRS Report R44638, Corporate Tax Integration and Tax
Reform, by Jane G. Gravelle. That report examines the effects of different tax treatment of the
corporate and noncorporate sectors, the effect of tax preferences, the treatment of debt finance,
and the treatment of foreign source income. Estimates suggest that there is little overall difference
between corporate and noncorporate investment. A larger share of corporate assets benefits from
tax preferences. Only a quarter of shares in U.S. firms is held by taxable individuals; the
remainder is held by tax-exempt and largely tax-exempt pension and retirement accounts,
nonprofits, and foreigners. Additionally, tax rates on individual dividends and capital gains are
lower than ordinary rates.
Effective tax rates across assets differ markedly, with intangible assets most favored and
structures least favored. Debt is treated favorably in both the corporate and noncorporate sectors,
with large differences and in many cases negative tax rates. Differences in taxes affecting
dividend payout choices or realization of capital gains on stock appear to be small because of low
tax rates.
The report outlines several approaches to integration. Full integration would address both
dividends and retained earnings. Tax could be imposed at the shareholder level with allocation of
income and withholding (a modified partnership treatment). Credits for withheld taxes would be
provided to shareholders, and credits could be made nonrefundable for tax-exempt and foreign
shareholders. A different full integration approach would eliminate shareholder taxes and tax only
at the firm level. A third would tax at the shareholder level and not the firm by imposing ordinary
rates and taxing not only dividends and realized capital gains but also unrealized gains by
marking shares to market prices (i.e., mark-to-market). Partial integration focuses on dividends
and could provide either a dividend deduction by the firm (with a withholding tax and credits) or
a dividend exclusion to the shareholder. Disallowing interest deductions in full or in part could be
combined with most proposals.
The report compares these proposals with respect to impact on revenue, administrative feasibility,
and effects on both traditional and international tax choices. Shareholder allocation or dividend
deductions with refundable credits produce relatively large revenue losses, as does mark-tomarket.
Nonrefundability and making modifications in mark-to-market can substantially reduce
these revenue losses. Most proposals would have modest efficiency gains or losses. Mark-tomarket
would tax economic income and potentially produce a number of efficiency gains but may
not be feasible on administrative grounds. Disallowing or restricting deductions for interest would
lead to efficiency gains on a number of margins and provide revenue to help achieve revenueneutral
reforms.